Example
Consider the preference schedule below, in which a company’s advertising team is voting on five different advertising slogans, called A, B, C, D, and E here for simplicity.
Initial votes
|
3 |
4 |
4 |
6 |
2 |
1 |
1st choice |
B |
C |
B |
D |
B |
E |
2nd choice |
C |
A |
D |
C |
E |
A |
3rd choice |
A |
D |
C |
A |
A |
D |
4th choice |
D |
B |
A |
E |
C |
B |
5th choice |
E |
E |
E |
B |
D |
C |
If this was a plurality election, note that B would be the winner with 9 first-choice votes, compared to 6 for D, 4 for C, and 1 for E.
There are total of 3+4+4+6+2+1 = 20 votes. A majority would be 11 votes. No one yet has a majority, so we proceed to elimination rounds.
Round 1: We make our first elimination. Choice A has the fewest first-place votes, so we remove that choice
|
3 |
4 |
4 |
6 |
2 |
1 |
1st choice |
B |
C |
B |
D |
B |
E |
2nd choice |
C |
|
D |
C |
E |
|
3rd choice |
|
D |
C |
|
|
D |
4th choice |
D |
B |
|
E |
C |
B |
5th choice |
E |
E |
E |
B |
D |
C |
We then shift everyone’s choices up to fill the gaps. There is still no choice with a majority, so we eliminate again.
|
3 |
4 |
4 |
6 |
2 |
1 |
1st choice |
B |
C |
B |
D |
B |
E |
2nd choice |
C |
D |
D |
C |
E |
D |
3rd choice |
D |
B |
C |
E |
C |
B |
4th choice |
E |
E |
E |
B |
D |
C |
Round 2: We make our second elimination. Choice E has the fewest first-place votes, so we remove that choice, shifting everyone’s options to fill the gaps.
|
3 |
4 |
4 |
6 |
2 |
1 |
1st choice |
B |
C |
B |
D |
B |
D |
2nd choice |
C |
D |
D |
C |
C |
B |
3rd choice |
D |
B |
C |
B |
D |
C |
Notice that the first and fifth columns have the same preferences now, we can condense those down to one column.
|
5 |
4 |
4 |
6 |
1 |
1st choice |
B |
C |
B |
D |
D |
2nd choice |
C |
D |
D |
C |
B |
3rd choice |
D |
B |
C |
B |
C |
Now B has 9 first-choice votes, C has 4 votes, and D has 7 votes. Still no majority, so we eliminate again.
Round 3: We make our third elimination. C has the fewest votes.
|
5 |
4 |
4 |
6 |
1 |
1st choice |
B |
D |
B |
D |
D |
2nd choice |
D |
B |
D |
B |
B |
Condensing this down:
|
9 |
11 |
1st choice |
B |
D |
2nd choice |
D |
B |
D has now gained a majority, and is declared the winner under IRV.
The following video provides another view of the example from above.
https://youtu.be/C-X-6Lo_xUQ?list=PL1F887D3B8BF7C297
Try It
Consider again this election. Find the winner using IRV.
|
44 |
14 |
20 |
70 |
22 |
80 |
39 |
1st choice |
G |
G |
G |
M |
M |
B |
B |
2nd choice |
M |
B |
|
G |
B |
M |
|
3rd choice |
B |
M |
|
B |
G |
G |
|
Here is an overview video that provides the definition of IRV, as well as an example of how to determine the winner of an election using IRV.
https://youtu.be/6axH6pcuyhQ
Example
Let’s return to our City Council Election.
|
342 |
214 |
298 |
1st choice |
Elle |
Don |
Key |
2nd choice |
Don |
Key |
Don |
3rd choice |
Key |
Elle |
Elle |
In this election, Don has the smallest number of first place votes, so Don is eliminated in the first round. The 214 people who voted for Don have their votes transferred to their second choice, Key.
|
342 |
512 |
1st choice |
Elle |
Key |
2nd choice |
Key |
Elle |
|
|
So Key is the winner under the IRV method.
We can immediately notice that in this election, IRV violates the Condorcet Criterion, since we determined earlier that Don was the Condorcet winner. On the other hand, the temptation has been removed for Don’s supporters to vote for Key; they now know their vote will be transferred to Key, not simply discarded.
In the following video, we provide the example from above where we find that the IRV method violates the Condorcet Criterion in an election for a city council seat.
https://youtu.be/BCRaYCU28Ro?list=PL1F887D3B8BF7C297
Example
Consider the voting system below.
|
37 |
22 |
12 |
29 |
1st choice |
Adams |
Brown |
Brown |
Carter |
2nd choice |
Brown |
Carter |
Adams |
Adams |
3rd choice |
Carter |
Adams |
Carter |
Brown |
In this election, Carter would be eliminated in the first round, and Adams would be the winner with 66 votes to 34 for Brown.
Now suppose that the results were announced, but election officials accidentally destroyed the ballots before they could be certified, and the votes had to be recast. Wanting to “jump on the bandwagon,” 10 of the voters who had originally voted in the order Brown, Adams, Carter change their vote to favor the presumed winner, changing those votes to Adams, Brown, Carter.
|
47 |
22 |
2 |
29 |
1st choice |
Adams |
Brown |
Brown |
Carter |
2nd choice |
Brown |
Carter |
Adams |
Adams |
3rd choice |
Carter |
Adams |
Carter |
Brown |
In this re-vote, Brown will be eliminated in the first round, having the fewest first-place votes. After transferring votes, we find that Carter will win this election with 51 votes to Adams’ 49 votes! Even though the only vote changes made
favored Adams, the change ended up costing Adams the election. This doesn’t seem right, and introduces our second fairness criterion: